Sanctuary and Survival:
The PLO in Lebanon
Boulder: Westview Press, 1990
by Rex Brynen
1) Dilemmas of Sanctuary
On 1 January 1965--a date now commemorated by Palestinians
each year as the birthdate of al-thawra, the
Palestinian "revolution"--a short communique
by the heretofore unknown al-`Asifa forces
announced from Beirut the successful completion of
its first guerrilla raid into Israel. In fact, the
group that had set out from `Ayn al-Hilwa refugee
camp in Sidon the previous night had never reached
the Lebanese-Israeli frontier, let alone their intended
target of an Israeli water-pumping station. Instead,
they had been immediately arrested by the Lebanese
security forces.[1 ]
Inauspicious as this beginning was, the event spoke
volumes about the emerging relationship between Lebanon
and the al-muqawama al-filastiniyya--the "Palestinian
resistance"--that would so very strongly shape
the trajectories of both over the next two decades.
Quite apart from the remarkable ideological importance
of the issue in Arab domestic and regional politics,
Lebanon was, by the simple fact of geography, inevitably
destined to be affected by the conflict in Palestine.
In 1948, the marginal participation of the Lebanese
army in what was to become its first and last foray
into the Arab-Israeli wars had signaled the reluctant
recognition by Lebanon's political leadership of their
country's status as a confrontation state. The eventual
arrival of over one hundred thousand Palestinian refugees
confirmed the connection. For a while, Beirut itself
became home to al-Hajj Amin al-Husayni, the former
Mufti of Jerusalem whose Arab Higher Committee had
constituted the chief leadership of the Palestinian
movement during the British Mandate. As elsewhere
in the diaspora, Palestinian community organizations
were slowly established or re-established in Lebanon
through the 1950s and early 1960s, responding both
to social needs and national aspirations. It was during
this period too that a new generation of Palestinian
political activists began to emerge, their activities
evident within Beirut student unions, in the Arab
Nationalists' Movement, and in the irregular appearance
of the magazine Filastinuna ("Our Palestine"),
clandestinely published by the same al-Fateh
movement that lay behind the acts of al-`Asifa.
On the eve of the June 1967 Arab-Israeli war, however,
none of this was quite so apparent. The Palestinian
movement was still weak and fragmented from the disaster
it had suffered in 1948. Despite the formation by
the Arab League of a "Palestinian entity"--the
Palestine Liberation Organization (PLO)--in 1964,
the modern Palestinian nationalist movement still
only existed as such in a latent and nebulous sense.
In Lebanon, as elsewhere, the authorities maintained
tight rein over all Palestinian nationalist activities.
After June 1967, all this was to change with astonishing
rapidity. Advocating popular armed struggle (al-kifah
al-musallah al-sha`bi) against Israel, the activism
of small Palestinian guerrilla groups (fida'iyyin)
contrasted sharply with the failure of Arab regular
armies. The result was rapid growth in their numbers
and popular support. By 1968-69 they had taken control
of the PLO, revolutionizing that organization from
within, and restructuring the nature of relations
between the Palestinians and the Arab confrontation
states.
The repercussions of this for Lebanon were immense.
By November 1969 the new dynamics of Palestinian-Lebanese
relations had produced the "Cairo Agreement,"
a formal agreement between the PLO and government
of Lebanon regulating their mutual relations. Under
its terms the Lebanese government accepted the legitimacy
of the PLO's presence in Lebanon and the pursuit of
its struggle against Israel from Lebanese territory
"within the framework of Lebanese sovereignty
and security." A year later, in September 1970,
the government of Jordan began its suppression of
Palestinian nationalist activities there. With this,
Lebanon soon became the headquarters and primary operational
base of the PLO. Through the 1970s and early 1980s
that base would see continuous if uneven expansion,
such that by the spring of 1982 it constituted a virtual
Palestinian "para-state" in Lebanon.[2]
The challenges faced by the Palestinian nationalist
movement in safeguarding and expanding this presence
in Lebanon over the years would be severe. The PLO
would twice clash with the Lebanese army, in 1969
and again in 1973. Later it would find itself engulfed
by the Lebanese civil war (1975-76), and the target
of Syrian military intervention (1976). It would experience
escalating military conflict with Israel and its Lebanese
proxies in south Lebanon, including Israeli invasions
in 1978 and 1982. Of all these, only the latter would
succeed in destroying Palestinian bases and institutions
in south Lebanon and forcing the withdrawal of PLO
fighters and cadres from Beirut.
It is the position of the PLO in Lebanon, from its
consolidation in the late 1960s to the Israeli invasion
of June 1982 and beyond, that represents the focus
of the study. It will examine how, during the critical
period from the Cairo agreement to the Lebanese war,
the PLO sought to safeguard both its organizational
presence in Lebanon and the well-being of the Palestinian
community resident there. It will identify the objectives
and actions that comprised the PLO's "Lebanese"
policy, and the often problematic process whereby
such policy was formulated and implemented. And it
will assess the effectiveness of the PLO in achieving
its aims, assessing the extent to which the PLO's
post-1982 difficulties in Lebanon are rooted in the
legacies of earlier actions and experience.
As will be seen, the PLO's problems of maintaining
a secure Lebanese base were to prove both complex
and intense. Yet it can be argued that, in the broadest
sense, they have not been entirely unique. Rather
they reflect the existence of the dilemmas faced by
any insurgent group which utilizes in its struggle
the physical and political shelter offered by a "sanctuary
state."
Insurgents and Sanctuaries
A Framework for Analysis
"Sanctuary"--that is to say, a secure
base area within which an insurgent group is able
to organize the politico-military infrastructure needed
to support its activities--is central to the process
of insurgency. It is from such sanctuaries that operations
against the enemy are planned and launched. It is
from here that troops and cadres are trained, logistics
maintained, and leadership exercised--all relatively
free from enemy interference. The structures and institutions
of the insurgent state-in-waiting may first take form
within the shelter of a sanctuary area. And it is
here that (in the classic model of guerrilla warfare)
guerrilla resources are built up to the point where
the insurgents can challenge their opponent in semi-regular
warfare. It comes as no surprise, then, to find that
many guerrilla leaders--Mao Tse-Tung, Vo Nguyen Giap,
Che Guevara, to name but a few--have devoted considerable
attention to the importance of base areas in their
writings. Mao, for example, identified the establishment
of base areas as one of seven "fundamental steps"
necessary to a successful guerrilla campaign:
A guerrilla base may be defined as an area, strategically
located, in which the guerrillas can carry out their
duties of training, self-preservation and development.
[The] ability to fight a war without a rear area
is a fundamental characteristic of guerrilla warfare,
but this does not mean that guerrillas can exist
and function over a long period of time without
the development of base areas.[3]
Insurgent sanctuaries may differ widely in terms
of geography, usage, and political context. Some--what
we might term internal sanctuaries--are so-called
"liberated zones" sited within the territory
in contention. Generally these bases are established
in areas of high insurgent activity and entrenched
insurgent political influence near to major political
targets, yet protected by geography (mountains, heavy
vegetation, or otherwise protective terrain) or confused
boundaries of administrative responsibility and political
loyalty.[4 ]
The partisans in Yugoslavia, the Red Army in China,
the struggle of the Viet-Minh against the French,
and the revolution against Batista in Cuba all represent
examples of successful insurgencies based almost entirely
on internal sanctuaries of this type. Still, such
examples are relatively rare.[5] More often insurgents
opt for (or are forced into) significant dependence
on external sanctuaries, utilizing the very
different shelter of international borders by establishing
major base areas within the territory of a proximate,
but politically distinct, sanctuary state.
Some are careless or even involuntary hosts, unwilling
or unable to deny use of their their territory to
the insurgents--hence the use of Cambodian and Laotian
territory by the Viet-Cong during the Vietnam war.
In many other cases, the extension of shelter to insurgents
is a deliberate act of policy motivated by ideological
sympathy, outside rewards or pressures, or in pursuit
of more complex realpolitik objectives (especially
as a tool of covert punishment or destabilization).
Under such conditions it is the principal of state
sovereignty, coupled with the willingness and ability
of the host state to defend its territory from incursions
by the insurgents' opponent, that generates the necessary
protection.
What factors contribute to insurgent use of and reliance
on sanctuary states? A necessary condition is, of
course, the availability of states either willing
to perform the sanctuary role or (such as Cambodia
during the Vietnam war) unable to avoid it. Above
and beyond this, four additional variables of importance
can be identified.
The first of these is availability of internal sanctuary.
Because of the psychological and political value of
"liberated zones" as a symbols of insurgent
power, internal sanctuaries are generally preferable
to external ones. If, however, "a regime effectively
prevents an insurgent movement from organizing within
a target area, external support, in terms of sanctuary
and freedom of movement, becomes critical."[6]
So too when and where faced by unsuitable terrain
or an unsupportive target population, insurgents will
be correspondingly more reliant on the shelter of
a sanctuary state.
The proximity and access offered by potential
external sanctuaries is also an important variable.
When utilizing the shelter of an external sanctuary,
insurgent groups are more likely to prefer sanctuary
states that are near to the conflict zone and which
give easy geographical entry to the most important
areas of insurgent activity. More distant sanctuaries
might provide propaganda and organizational facilities,
but are much less effective as operational bases.
Levels of sanctuary support are also likely to affect
the choice of sanctuary areas. Tolerance or even active
support by the government of the sanctuary state to
the insurgent group will increase insurgent use of
that sanctuary. Conversely, opposition to the insurgents'
presence and activities will have the opposite effect--subject
to the government's ability to extend its authority
to the (often remote) border regions from which the
insurgents seek to operate.
Similarly, the existence of popular support within
the sanctuary state, of a population willing to provide
the insurgents with recruits and other forms of assistance,
will increase insurgent use of that sanctuary. This
is particularly important when (as is often the case)
the population shares ethnic, religious or other significant
characteristics with the insurgents--perhaps even
comprising sympathetic refugees displaced from the
conflict zone itself.
All of these factors can be found at work in the
illustrative case of the 1974-75 Kurdish insurgency
in Iraq. Following the collapse of an earlier 1970
autonomy agreement between the central government
and the leadership of the Kurdish Democratic Party,
fighting once more erupted in Iraqi Kurdistan. Despite
the formidable nature of the region's mountainous
terrain, assertive military action by the well-armed
Iraqi armed forces rendered many of the traditional
bases of Kurdish insurgency untenable. Limited sanctuary
was potentially available to the Iraqi Kurdish guerrillas
(Pesh Merga) among the supportive populations of neighboring
Syrian, Turkish, and Iranian Kurdistan. Of these,
however, Turkey had long suppressed the Kurdish movement
among its own Kurdish population, and hence denied
its territory to the Pesh Merga as best it could.
Syria (hostile to the rival Ba`thist regime in Baghdad)
did grant the KDP propaganda support and use of offices
in Damascus, but was reluctant to allow armed guerrillas
to operate from its territory. Iran, in contrast,
provided the Pesh Merga with both sanctuary and extensive
material assistance, enabling the Kurds to mount several
major counter-offensives. This continued until negotiations
between the Shah of Iran and Iraq's Saddam Husayn
brought an end to their long-simmering border dispute
over the Shatt al-`Arab waterway in March 1975. With
this, Iran immediately withdrew its aid and shelter
to the Pesh Merga, causing an immediate collapse of
the insurgency.[7]
Imperatives and Dilemmas of Insurgent-Sanctuary
Relations
The importance of sanctuary--and hence of sanctuary
states--to insurgent movements thus becomes clear.
Excepting perhaps the strategies of coup d'état
or spontaneous insurrection, the possession of secure
base areas becomes a sine qua non of the insurgents'
success. As Ibrahim Abu Lughod has noted:
One of the more important postulates of wars of
national liberation is the support revolutionaries
are able to obtain, politically, morally and material,
from the international system.... It is virtually
impossible to think of the successful wars of national
liberation of Algeria, Mozambique and Vietnam without
assigning important roles to Egypt and Tunis, Tanzania
and Zambia, and China, as well as the Soviet Union.
In all such cases, the neighboring country served
as a hinterland for the revolutionaries, whom it
provided with sanctuaries and so forth, while at
the same time it provided them with the political
support necessary to carry out the struggle internationally.
In certain cases the neighboring countries provided
the staging area for the transmission of weapons,
material and manpower to the country waging its
war of national liberation. In short, then, the
principle can be stated simply: It is imperative
for the population engaged in a war of national
liberation to have the full material and political
support of an external state.[8]
In Abu Lughod's view, "once a population achieves
a certain level of mobilization and `revolutionary'
consciousness, an adjacent territorial base controlled
by an ally is crucial."
The extent to which the West Bank and Gaza Strip
are mobilized today is evident... There is a logical
need for an established state, adjacent to Palestine,
that will provide support, succor and haven for
the beleaguered population of the West Bank and
Gaza Strip. The extent to which the Palestinians
succeed in securing such a terrain will have an
important impact on the outcome of national resistance
in the West Bank and Gaza.[9]
Conversely, the loss of such bases through the loss
or withdrawal of sanctuary will almost invariably
have a devastating--and perhaps fatal--effect on the
insurgents in question.[ Aware of this dangerous possibility,
Che Guevara warned that "unconditional help should
not be expected from a government, whether friendly
or simply negligent, that allows its territory to
be used as a base of operations"; on the contrary,
insurgents should treat the situation with a degree
of caution and discipline "as if... in a completely
hostile camp."[10 ]The susceptibility of the
Irish Republican Army in Northern Ireland to the changing
political environment in the Irish Republic during
the 1920s and 1930s illustrates the point, as does
the collapse of the communist insurgency in Greece
after the closure of the Yugoslavian frontier in 1948.
For the Kurds, it was a lesson underscored once more
in the 1980s. Having fought against the Iraqi government
(with significant success) almost from the outset
of the Iran-Iraq War in 1980, Iraqi Kurds again found
themselves abruptly cut off from Iranian aid and shelter
when the latter agreed to a ceasefire in August 1988.
With this, another Kurdish insurgency collapsed amid
a brutal Iraqi offensive in Iraqi Kurdistan.[11]
Despite the importance of sanctuary states to insurgent
movements, little analytical attention has been devoted
to examining relations between the two, or to delineating
how insurgent movements can and do respond to the
dilemmas noted above. In part this reflects the fact
that many of the most important and prolific theoreticians
of revolutionary warfare (Lenin, Mao, Guevara, Giap)
led guerrilla campaigns not involving significant
use of an external sanctuary. It also reflects a sometimes
deliberate obscuration of the question by insurgents
themselves, with the role of external support suppressed
amid emphasis on revolutionary action and self-reliance,
or hidden by the secrecy under which insurgent-sanctuary
diplomacy is so often conducted. As a consequence,
the importance of sanctuaries-- although almost universally
noted--is rarely analyzed in any depth. Accounts of
particular cases of insurgent-sanctuary interaction
remain largely descriptive, whilst the general question
of insurgent policy towards sanctuary states has remained
all but unexamined.[12]
One rare exception to this pattern is the treatment
extended to sanctuary behavior by Douglas Anglin and
Timothy Shaw in the context of a broader examination
of Zambian foreign policy.[13] Here they suggest that
Zambia's attitude towards southern African liberation
movements should be seen in terms of its efforts to
minimize the risks associated with providing transit
facilities and other forms of assistance. In other
words, Zambia's support as a sanctuary state was tempered
by its vulnerability to the superior military power
of Rhodesia and South Africa (Figure 1.1). Whenever
the activities of southern African liberation movements
in and from Zambia threatened to invite unacceptable
retaliation (Z1), Lusaka restricted those activities
so as to reduce the risk to an acceptable level (Z0).
Conversely, as Zambia's vulnerability to retaliation
(i.e., the potential cost of the insurgent presence)
declined (Z2), controls were relaxed and support for
southern African liberation movements stepped up (Z3).[
]
![](brynen2_01.gif)
Figure 1.1: Sanctuary Behavior
Here Anglin and Shaw concur with two hypotheses about
sanctuary behavior proposed by one of the few other
analysts to examine insurgent-sanctuary interaction,
Bard O'Neill. Specifically, O'Neill (drawing upon
the Palestinian case) has suggested that "if
a sanctuary country is clearly in a position of military
inferiority vis-à-vis the target state and
lacks allies who will come to its defense, the costs
inflicted by counterinsurgency reprisals are likely
to increase," leading in turn to a situation
wherein the host "defenseless against reprisals
but perceiving itself to be militarily equal to or
stronger than the insurgents, will curb the latter's
operations as the costs of retaliation escalate."[
14]
Indeed, herein lies the heart of the insurgents'
dilemma. For while sanctuary provides important, perhaps
indispensable, benefits for an insurgent movement,
the granting of sanctuary may involve considerable
costs for the sanctuary state and the regime that
rules it. This in turn adversely affects insurgent-sanctuary
relations--and hence threatens the availability of
sanctuary itself.
Insurgents and the State
The potential costs faced by a sanctuary state
are many. To begin with, the presence of the insurgents
may invite "hot-pursuit" raids and other
military action against them within the sanctuary's
territory by the insurgents' opponent. It will also
almost certainly involve some degree of pressure on
their host to end its granting of sanctuary. Such
pressure may range from diplomatic protests by the
insurgents' opponent to punishment-strikes and possibly
even armed intervention.
Furthermore, the activities of heavily-armed and
difficult-to-control insurgents may adversely affect
domestic public order. This is particularly the case
if the insurgents' base area begins to assume political
autonomy from the sanctuary state itself, threatening
the state's ability to assert sovereignty over the
insurgents and their activities on national soil.[15]
The problems created by the presence of large numbers
of armed insurgents among a sanctuary state's civilian
population are further exacerbated by the fact that
insurgents, by their very nature, reject many of the
conventional symbols of state authority. Insurgents
who are little more than mercenaries or brigands can
be expected to act as such. Revolutionary combatants,
on the other hand, may (justifiably or otherwise)
view the activities of local security forces to control
their activities as part of a counter-revolutionary
effort to liquidate their struggle, and resist them
accordingly.
The relative magnitude of such costs may be amplified
by the context in which they occur. For poor, weak
sanctuary states or those already suffering from a
degree of political instability--categories embracing
much of the third world--the strain of granting sanctuary
can threaten to overwhelm.
Such has been the case among the Frontline states
of southern Africa. There, in an effort to weaken
the sanctuary and support given to the African National
Congress (ANC), South West African People's Organization
(SWAPO), and other southern African liberation movements,
the Republic of South Africa has embarked on a major
campaign of indirect economic pressure, subversion,
and direct military attacks against Angola, Botswana,
Lesotho, Zimbabwe and Mozambique. Between 1980 and
1986 Angola and Mozambique (the chief targets of Pretoria's
so-called "Total Strategy") suffered an
estimated $25 billion in economic damage and a staggering
total of 735,000 war-related deaths, in addition to
the displacement of almost 2 million refugees.[16
]By the mid-1980s such pressure had forced many of
the Frontline states to negotiate bilateral security
agreements with South Africa. Thus in February 1984
South Africa and Angola agreed to a ceasefire (the
Lusaka Accord) and joint patrols to halt SWAPO infiltration
into South African-occupied Namibia. One month later,
Mozambique and South Africa signed the so-called Nikomati
Accord, under which both pledged "not to allow
their respective territories, territorial waters or
air space to be used as a base, thoroughfare, or in
any other way by any state, government, foreign military
forces, organizations or individuals which plan or
prepare to commit acts of violence, terrorism or aggression
against the territorial integrity or political independence
of the other or may threaten the security of its inhabitants."[17]
Mozambique--a country long committed to the struggle
against South African apartheid --promptly
expelled ANC cadres from its territory.
The central point to be made here is that there exists,
within any set of insurgent-sanctuary relations, considerable
potential for divergence between the insurgents' raison
de la révolution and the sanctuary's raison
d'état. And for the insurgents involved,
the potential for conflict between the two, coupled
with the political and military value of sanctuary,
poses a unique set of policy imperatives. Specifically,
insurgent groups must formulate and implement policies
whereby their position within a sanctuary is safeguarded
or improved. To do otherwise is to risk serious damage
to insurgent-sanctuary relations, and possibly the
crippling or destruction of the insurgent movement
itself.
Precisely how can this be achieved? If, as suggested
earlier, sanctuary behavior is a response to real
and potential insurgent-related costs, insurgent policy
towards sanctuary states must largely be aimed at
manipulating those costs in a favorable manner. The
most immediate response would be to adopt what might
be termed a strategy of restraint, reducing
insurgent-related costs below the level at which containment
and suppression would otherwise occur. The voluntary
restriction of cross-border activity, strict codes
of conduct for guerrilla personnel, and limitations
on the display and deployment of weapons would all
comprise elements of such an approach. The deliberate
low profile of the Algerian Front de Libération
Nationale (FLN) in Tunisia during the Algerian
revolution--a policy designed to minimize French pressure
upon that state--represented precisely such a strategy.
So too did the willingness of the KDP to refrain from
nationalist agitation in Iranian Kurdistan during
the 1974-75 Kurdish war.[18 ]
Insurgents might also find that a coincidence of
interests (or simple bribery) provides the grounds
for securing local allies within the sanctuary state.
Such allies--influential political parties, associations,
interest groups, ethnic or religious groups, or even
factions within the government itself--might then
provide direct material support, and exert political
pressure to obtain greater regime tolerance and support
for insurgent activities. The efforts of Sri Lankan
Tamil separatists to secure sanctuary and influence
Indian policy through ties to Tamil ethnic and political
leaders in India's Tamil Nadu state represents one
(albeit largely unsuccessful) use of such a strategy
of internal alliance in the 1980s.
Neither a strategy of internal alliance nor one of
restraint, however, is unproblematic. Internal alliances
may create dangerous entanglements. Tied to a domestic
actor by such an alliance, insurgents may find themselves
unwillingly dragged into domestic political issues.
At worst, their internal alliance might be taken as
evidence of insurgent interference in the internal
affairs of the host regime, and hence received as
a further cost by sanctuary decision-makers.
As for a strategy of restraint, it requires that
self-restraining guerrilla actions will be appreciated
as such by state decision-makers. To assure this it
may be necessary to open and maintain close dialogue,
even a formal framework for mutual consultation. Such
communication may even become an ancillary
strategy in itself, serving the additional purpose
of reducing the likelihood of "accidental"
deterioration in insurgent-sanctuary relations caused
by misperceived acts by one party or the other.
The effectiveness of self-restraint is also mediated
by the retaliatory activity of the insurgents' opponent,
assuming as it does that retaliation is a function
of insurgent activity. If this is the case, restraint
risks undermining the very raison d'être
of an insurgent group, generating conditions under
which the requirements of maintaining sanctuary (the
reduction of military activity so as to reduce retaliatory
action against the insurgents' host) may directly
contradict the requirements of armed struggle. Conversely,
should the insurgents' opponent adopt a policy of
deliberate, massive and disproportionate punishment
attacks against the sanctuary regardless of insurgent
activity, the effectiveness of insurgent restraint
will be sharply limited.
Finally, a strategy of restraint assumes that costs
are transitory, and hence mutable. But are they? To
a significant extent, the costs of enemy retaliation
and guerrilla banditry are. But other insurgent-related
costs may be structural in nature, thus posing a significantly
greater challenge to the course of insurgent-sanctuary
relations.
Insurgency and Revolution
Not all insurgencies are created equal. Some lack
any significant social content, merely seeking to
replace one political elite with another within the
framework of the same socio-economic system. Others,
however, seek to transform the socio-economic as well
as political nature of their own societies. Such revolutionary
insurgencies have a far more unsettling effect on
the regional and international system.[19] Because
of this, insurgents who are revolutionaries face greater
difficulties in maintaining sanctuary.
The political economy of revolution affects the problem
of insurgent-sanctuary relations most seriously through
the threat of contagion. By their very nature revolutions
pose a standing challenge to the socio-economic and
political structure of states, and more specifically
to the social, economic, and political positions of
their dominant classes. To the extent that the structures
they challenge at home are replicated elsewhere, their
threat expands beyond the immediate borders of the
conflict area. The insurgents cannot advance a sociopolitical
agenda for their own country (agrarian reform, redistribution
of wealth, democratization, and so forth) without
potentially causing similar questions to be raised
within the host sanctuary. So too revolutionary ideology,
organization and the notion of armed struggle may
spread to groups within the sanctuaries in which they
shelter.
In short, the costs of hosting revolutionary insurgents
cannot simply be reduced to transitory costs imposed
on an abstract state. Whether directly or by catalyzing
latent forces within the host society, insurgents
may spur developments fundamentally challenging to
those in positions of political and economic power.
In other words, the mere presence of a revolutionary
movement within a dissonant state and society constitutes
a structural threat to those who rule it--varying
only with the dissonance between the revolutionary's
program and the maintenance structures of the local
sociopolitical order, and existing regardless of the
activities of the movement and the direct imposition
of outside costs. In turn, such a challenge to the
status quo raises the regional repercussions of the
insurgents' struggle and aggravates the problem of
external intervention--quite likely in any case, but
now doubly so.[20]
For the PLO this lesson was bitterly learned in 1970-71.
At that time the Hashemite regime in Jordan, having
suffered heavily from both Israeli attacks and the
activities of the PLO, moved to suppress the latter
in a bloody civil war that cost many thousands of
casualties and brought to an end the PLO's effective
presence in the country which had been its most important
sanctuary. The costs of Israeli punishment attacks
and the ill-disciplined behavior of the fida'iyyin
provided major reasons for suppression. But of equal
or greater importance than this was the threat that
the Palestinian movement in and of itself represented
to the stability of the conservative Hashemite monarchy.[21]
Created by British colonial policy in 1921, the monarchy
rested on the twin bases of East Bank (Transjordanian)
tribal allegiances and a loyal army. Since its annexation
of the Palestinian West Bank after 1948, the regime
had sought to suppress most manifestations of a "Palestinian"
identity among the Palestinians who comprised a majority
or near-majority of its population. Jordanian foreign
policy had been suspicious of radical pan-Arabism
and closely aligned with the West. In this context,
the rise of a radical Palestinian nationalist movement
after 1967 challenged the very foundations of the
regime. And it was precisely those elements most challenged--the
monarchy, tribal leaders, the Transjordanian officer
corps and political elite--who most favored suppression
of the PLO. Anxious to preserve the status quo, their
stance was passively supported by conservative Arab
states alarmed at the rapid growth and influence of
the fida'iyyin, and more openly by Israel and
the United States. Essentially the "Black September"
of 1970 was the military reaction of a conservative
elite faced with a potential revolutionary threat
to its power and position.
In policy terms, therefore, insurgents face particular
difficulties in maintaining sanctuary to the degree
in which their programs threaten the social and political
status quo in the host state. The strategies of restraint
and communications might be utilized to a limited
extent. In contexts where the very existence of the
revolutionary movement within the sanctuary state
represents a major cost to sanctuary decision-makers,
however, the revolutionaries are constrained in the
degree to which they can "manage" relations
by restricting insurgent-related costs.
Instead, insurgents might seek to avoid suppression
through reliance on armed force. In some cases, the
military power of the insurgents may outweigh the
coercive ability of the sanctuary state, allowing
insurgents to impose their activities on an otherwise
unwilling host. Under such conditions an insurgent
movement has the option of adopting an offensive posture,
using its resources to overthrow (or helping others
to overthrow) the host government with the aim of
replacing it with a more supportive regime. But it
is seldom that such circumstances arise; insurgents
only rarely have military capabilities superior to
those of their host state, and lacking these the contribution
of the insurgents is only likely to be decisive in
situations already pregnant with political instability
and potential domestic revolution. Still, historical
cases of such a strategy of offense do exist,
including the PLO's own unsuccessful calls for the
overthrow of the Hashemite regime in Jordan in 1970-71.
A more likely alternative is a strategy of defense
whereby insurgents prepare to protect their status
by force. Such a strategy seeks to increase the costs
of suppression to an unacceptable level, effectively
raising the threshold at which suppression might occur
by adding to it a deterrent threat. If deterrence
fails, the insurgents' military efforts are then aimed
at defending their essential base of operations.
The Challenge of Intervention
The discussion thus far has examined insurgent
responses to the potential threat posed by a sanctuary
state, or possibly by its allies or proxies. In Lebanon,
however, the PLO would in fact successfully resist
all domestic efforts to contain or crush it for more
than two decades after the June 1967 Arab-Israeli
war. Indeed, it was only suppressed--and temporarily
at that--by outside intervention by its opponent,
Israel, in June 1982.
At first glance, such intervention falls outside
the theoretical scope of insurgent-sanctuary relations
as defined and discussed here. But in terms of practical
policy, the strategic calculus of insurgent-sanctuary
relations and external threats of enemy intervention
are inextricably tied. For that reason, it is important
that the issue be explicitly addressed.
Of the several features linking the internal and
external threats, the first and most apparent is perhaps
what might be termed "responsibility." Any
country which provides sanctuary to insurgents will
be held responsible (both under the terms of international
law, and in the practical realities of international
politics) for the insurgents' actions by the insurgents'
target. If sanctuary is not withdrawn, the insurgents'
host is likely to find itself subject to retaliatory
diplomatic, economic or military measures. Indeed,
the sanctuary state itself may become a primary focus
of military action by the insurgents' opponent--partly
to compel it to withdraw sanctuary, and partly because
it represents (in contrast to the elusive insurgents)
a clear target for engagement by regular armed forces.[22]
The greater the sanctuary's support for the insurgents
in question, the greater the likelihood and scope
of retaliation it will suffer. Conversely, if the
sanctuary evinces no support, and even claims an inability
to control the insurgents operating on and from its
territory, the greater too the likelihood of armed
intervention. Arguing that the sanctuary state lacks
both sovereignty over its own territory and the power
to assert its authority, the "enemy" may
well claim to itself the right of regional policeman,
and enter the sanctuary's territory at will to conduct
its own military operations.[23]
All of these factors can be seen at work in the South
African case, where coercive diplomacy, identification
of nationalist insurgency with its neighbors, and
the belief direct military action was necessary to
curb guerrilla infiltration all underpinned South
African pursuit of its "Total Strategy"
against the Frontline states. Even after the first
of these rationales had been removed by the Lusaka
and Nikomati accords, however, South African intervention
continued for more than four years. At one level,
military action against an external target provided
a visible (if marginally effective) response to the
government's inability to deal with rising levels
of domestic protest and resistance. At another, military
intervention acquired a virtual life of its own, rendering
southern Angola and Mozambique a chaotic and continuing
arena for the forceful deployment of South African
military might.[24]
Yet such intervention does not occur in a vacuum,
but rather in a critical international context. In
the South African case, for example, Soviet and Cuban
support for Angola increased the political and military
costs of Pretoria's military actions there, ultimately
forcing a revision in South African policy. Together
with other factors, this led to the December 1988
"tripartite agreement" providing for the
withdrawal of South African (and Cuban) troops from
Angola and the independence of Namibia.
It is here that a second link between intervention
and insurgent policy can be found. The ability of
one state (the "enemy") to inflict punishment
raids, massive retaliation, or invasion against another
("the sanctuary") is primarily constrained
by the local and international balance of power; not
only must the sanctuary state be so comparatively
weak that it cannot prevent or deter such attacks,
but the international system must allow it.[ ]During
the Algerian War, for example, France responded to
FLN use of Tunisian territory by claiming rights of
both "hot pursuit" and "riposte"
against the insurgents. Despite this, the political
costs of such activities (notably its February 1958
bombing of the Tunisian town of Sakiet-Sidi Yusif)
ultimately proved too high for France to bear, causing
it to refrain from major attacks on Tunisia for the
last four years of the war.[ ]Similarly, analysis
of Rhodesian decision-making in the 1960s and 1970s
has shown that, in the case of punishment attacks
by the white minority regime against Zambia, Mozambique,
Botswana, Angola, and Tanzania during the Zimbabwean
war of liberation, "the political costs involved
in such actions [were] the final sanction for their
execution."[25] If the international political
constraints are too great, the only choice remaining
to the insurgents' target is either to adopt less
open means of action (destabilization, covert penetration)[26]
or to refrain from retaliation and punishment of the
sanctuary altogether.
One possible insurgent response to this situation
is to seek support from outside states, particularly
from other regional states or the superpowers--a strategy
of external alliances designed to affect both
the regional environment and the dynamics of insurgent-sanctuary
relations. External allies can assist by placing pressure
on, or granting rewards to, the sanctuary state. They
may also strengthen insurgents directly, through the
supply of arms, funds, and intelligence. Finally,
external allies become valuable not only as direct
supporters and interceders on the insurgents' behalf,
but potentially as direct supporters of the sanctuary
state itself.[27] To the extent that they are able
to increase through diplomatic or military means the
sanctuary's will and capacity to deter and resist
enemy military action, they reduce its vulnerability
and the level of retaliatory pressure on it. This
in turn effectively reduces the cost of the insurgent
presence, and hence the likelihood of suppression.
Still, even external alliances may be insufficient
to prevent external intervention. As the locus of
conflict is forced backwards into heretofore secure
sanctuaries by enemy raids and covert action, an important
connection emerges between the insurgents' ability
to resist (or deter) enemy action and the state of
its local relations. Insurgents enjoying strong support
from the sanctuary state or internal allies within
it will be correspondingly more difficult to dislodge
by external intervention than will those which do
not. At the same time, the magnitude of insurgent-related
costs suffered by the sanctuary state climb--putting
the insurgent-sanctuary relationship to its most severe
test yet.
Insurgent Strategy and Decision-making
Although the identification of possible insurgent
responses ("restraint"; "communication";
"internal" and "external" alliances;
"defense" and "offense") suggests
the theoretical bases upon which insurgent policies
might be based, it does not in itself fully explain
either how and why a particular strategy or mix of
strategies might be adopted, or the effectiveness
with which they can be pursued. To do so requires
examination not only of the policy options available,
but also of the process whereby insurgent policy is
formulated, adopted, and implemented.
Unfortunately, despite an extensive literature on
insurgents and insurgencies, very little of this has
addressed the dynamics of insurgent policy-making.
In part this stems from the complexity of the subject
and the heterogeneity of insurgent movements. It also
reflects the historic dominance of a "realist"
paradigm of international relations which has centered
attention on the state and devalued the importance
of non-state actors in the international system. Finally,
there are the methodological obstacles which have
inhibited the study of third world foreign policy
in general, including secrecy and a lack of reliable
data regarding decision-making, and an excessive concentration
on the idiosyncratic role of political leaders.[28]
How then can we best approach the insurgent policy-making
process in the context of insurgent-sanctuary relations?
While the field lacks appropriate established models,
several studies of third world foreign policy in general,
and of Arab and PLO foreign policy in particular,
do suggest approaches whereby the topic might be addressed.
The first of these stresses the importance of objective
and systemic factors in foreign policy formulation,
rather than a reductionist focus on the role of third
world leaders.[29] Systemic and global constraints
play a fundamental role in shaping third world foreign
policy-making, both by limiting the menu of what can
be achieved, and by exerting a determining effect
on the degree to which chosen policies can attain
their objectives.
For insurgent movements, their limited ability to
affect the regional environment within which they
must operate heightens the constraining impact of
such systemic factors, forcing much of insurgent policy
to be event-driven. The importance of external support
(including sanctuary) renders them even more vulnerable
to regional political developments. This in turn has
important implications for the process of insurgent
decision-making. The dynamic circumstances of conducting
a guerrilla war may inhibit regularized decision-making.
As a consequence, high-level (and often ad-hoc) crisis
decision-making groups operating under conditions
of limited information may predominate amid the breakdown
or short-circuiting of formal decision-making procedures.[30]
A second set of factors that must be addressed pertains
to the importance of underlying social and political
processes in the shaping of foreign policy.[31] Despite
the foreign/domestic dichotomy sometimes assumed by
realist approaches to international relations, domestic
politics and socio-economic circumstances comprise
an inseparable part of the foreign policy process
in the third world. In turn, the weakness and permeability
of third world states generates circumstances under
which external constraints are transnationalized,
and reproduced within the social, economic and political
structures of "domestic" society.
Insurgent movements, lacking for the most part the
level of institutionalization achieved by even weak
third world states, are if anything even more deeply
affected by such factors. Almost all effective insurgent
movements are ultimately dependent on successful mobilization
of the domestic population, and hence highly sensitive
to its cleavages and substructures. Yet the domestic
politics of insurgency is easily transnationalized,
both by the regional repercussions of the insurgents'
struggle, and by the influence of external sponsors.
Within the movement itself, these transnational linkages
may be institutionalized by the creation of client
or proxy groups by interested outside actors. While
the event-sensitivity of insurgency requires from
insurgents dynamic responses to changing circumstances,
their simultaneous need to maintain a base of political
support may render them subject to the sorts of policy
immobilism characteristic of "constrained"
political regimes.[32]
A third area of importance relates to the impact
of the decision-making process itself.[33] While third
world leaders often enjoy considerable presidential
power, most neither control the decision-making process
nor monopolize it. As a result, the exercise of executive
power must be studies in the context of both institutional
and social variables.
This is particularly true of movements that, like
the PLO, have adopted a "national front"
model of organization. By including a variety of political
currents within the umbrella of a single broad-based
nationalist movement, a national front seeks to maximize
its appeal to all segments of its constituent population.
With all major groups represented within the decision-making
process, consensus-building becomes an important mechanism
for maintaining unity and minimizing internal conflict.
Indeed, given only limited ability to control member
organizations, majoritarian policies can only be adopted
at the risk of breaking up the essential inter-group
alliance. Decision-making thus commonly rests on compromise,
even issue-avoidance. Policies thus tend to be broad
in statement (to allow a variety of interpretations),
and policy changes incremental in nature, producing
a "lowest common denominator" outcome.[34]
It is in the interaction of these systemic-situational,
sociopolitical and organizational variables that insurgent
policy emerges. To a significant extent, however,
all coalesce into a single, multifaceted issue: the
question of insurgent authority.
Authority becomes an important key to understanding
the processes and constraints that shaped PLO policy
in Lebanon, and which shape policy formation in other
insurgent groups. The crucial aspect which distinguishes
insurgents from the regimes they oppose is, after
all, the exercise of sovereign authority over demarcated
territory. It is precisely to gain such sovereignty
and legal authority that insurgent groups struggle.
And, in the meantime, their ability to make and implement
policy decisions is deeply affected by its absence.
As Mohamed Selim has noted of non-state actors in
general, and the PLO in particular:
When they formulate foreign policies and operate
in the international system, nonstate actors confront
certain problems that state actors do not usually
experience. Nonstate actors, especially when they
take the form of a regional revolutionary movement
aspiring to alter the territorial status quo, lack
territorial political symbols to draw upon as a
basis for defining foreign policy. They confront
problems of control and legitimacy, factionalism,
visibility, durability, and maneuverability. Lacking
a territorial base and the conventional means of
conferring legitimacy, these actors find the legitimacy
of their representation to be always in question.
They must be concerned with the issue of being heard,
perceived, and recognized by nation-states and international
organizations. As the nonstate actors become more
visible and draw more international support, they
run the risk of being portrayed by their adversaries
as mavericks threatening international legitimacy.
Allies may also become a source of threat. Supporters
of nonstate actors expect a higher level of compliance
from them than they expect from their state clients.[35]
The provisional nature of insurgent authority thus
leaves insurgent policy open to challenge from both
within and without. To the extent that insurgents
lack constitutional-legal mechanisms of authority,
societal consensus on the legitimacy of insurgent
authority, and a monopoly on the legitimate use of
force to assure compliance, then, other means of legitimation
must be utilized. These might take the form of charismatic
leadership, of ideological appeals, or be based on
traditional symbols of authority such as the bonds
of shared cultural, religious or ethnic identity.
Insurgents may also approximate sovereignty in liberated
zones or sanctuaries through revolutionary decrees,
their own "laws" and legal procedures, and
perhaps even the formal trappings of a state-in-exile.
Such a resort to legal-bureaucratic and institutional
frameworks in insurgent base areas has both symbolic
value and, in a Weberian sense, serves as a mechanism
for the routinization and maintenance of (insurgent)
authority. Still, potential challenges to the authority
of the insurgent decision-making structure are not
eliminated. Nor, given the regional context within
which they operate, may insurgents be capable of reducing
their sensitivity[36] to external and internal pressures
on their own decision-making processes.
Vulnerability, however, is another matter--indeed,
it is an issue that will emerge as a central theme
of the study that follows. Like many insurgent movements,
the PLO has throughout its history faced severe (sometimes
irresistible) pressures to accommodate itself to external
demands. But while the constraints these have engendered
have been real and significant, they have served to
narrow Palestinian policy options rather than obviate
Palestinian political autonomy. As will become evident,
the Palestinian movement has expended considerable
energy in attempting to maintain its freedom from
outside "tutelage," Arab or otherwise. Indeed,
the principle of safeguarding the independence of
Palestinian decision-making is rooted in the very
concept of "Palestinianism" upon which the
post-1967 resurgence of the Palestinian movement would
be implicitly based. It is a principle upon which
each of the major independent Palestinian guerrilla
organizations agree, whatever their other substantial
political differences. Because of this, external threats
to the survival and independence of the PLO--whether
deriving from Israeli, Jordanian, Lebanese, Syrian,
Egyptian or other sources--have always tended to engender
a defensive unity of sorts. A similar reaction would
be evident in Lebanon too, in repeated crises and
confrontations with the Lebanese government, hostile
Lebanese militias, Syria, and Israel.
This has two important implications. First, it underlines
the importance of internal Palestinian politics in
PLO policy, politics that is real and indigenous even
if substantially affected by the regional political
environment. Second, it suggests why Lebanon would
prove so important to the PLO, and why over two decades
the PLO would make such strenuous efforts to preserve
its Lebanese base. Lebanon was important as a sanctuary
in general, as a training ground, as a base for Palestinian
military and political operations and a delivery point
for external supplies. Above and beyond this, however,
Lebanon would offer a Palestinian movement, long constrained
by the interests and pressures of others, its first
real political freedom. The Lebanese base would allow
the PLO to make decisions and act in a fashion that
was impossible elsewhere in the Arab world, and hence
to sustain the independence of Palestinian decision-making
it so prized. It would be in Lebanon, then, that the
Palestinians would become uniquely free to construct
their own institutions, to promote their own identity,
and to choose their own, Palestinian, paths
to their dream of national liberation.
Notes
1. Alan Hart, Arafat: Terrorist or Peacemaker?,
3rd ed. (London: Sidgwick and Jackson, 1987), p. 182.
Text of al-`Asifa Communique No. 1 in al-Watha'iq
al-filastiniyya al-`arabiyya 1965 [Arab Palestinian
Documents, henceforth APD] (Beirut: Institute
for Palestine Studies, annual), p. 1.
2. Rashid Khalidi, Under Siege: PLO Decisionmaking
During the 1982 War (New York: Columbia University
Press, 1986), pp. 28-29.
3. Mao Tse-Tung, On Guerilla Warfare, intro.
and trans. by Samuel B. Griffith (New York: Frederick
Praeger, 1961), p. 107. Similarly, for Vo Nguyen Giap
"a strong rear area is always the decisive factor
for victory in a revolutionary war"; see The
Military Art of People's War, ed. Russell Stetler
(New York: Monthly Review Press, 1970), pp. 87-92,
160, 179-181.
4. Robert W. McColl, "A Political Geography
of Revolution: China, Vietnam and Thailand,"
Journal of Conflict Resolution 11, 2 (June 1967):
153-156.
5. According to one study of twelve civil wars of
the 1970s outside actors provided (narrowly-defined)
"base facilities" to insurgents in 42% of
cases, representing 83% (five of six) of successful
insurgencies. Bertil Dunér, Military Intervention
in Civil Wars: the 1970s (Aldershot: Gower, 1985).
6. Bard E. O'Neill, Armed Struggle in Palestine:
A Political-Military Analysis (Boulder: Westview
Press, 1978), p. 160.
7. Chris Kutschera, Le mouvement national Kurde
(Paris: Flammarion, 1979), pp. 300-333.
8. Ibrahim Abu Lughod, "Lebanon and Palestine:
Some Contrasts in the Application of the Principles
of National Liberation," Arab Studies Quarterly
7, 4 (Fall 1985): 83.
9. Abu Lughod, "Lebanon and Palestine,"
p. 88.
10. Ernesto (Che) Guevara, Guerilla Warfare,
intro. and case studies by Brian Loveman and Thomas
M. Davies Jr. (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press,
1985), p. 157.
11. On the effect of changing sanctuary conditions
on the Irish, Greek and Kurdish cases, see: J. Bowyer
Bell, The Secret Army: The IRA 1916-79 (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press, 1980); Edgar O'Ballance, The Greek
Civil War 1944-49 (New York: Praeger 1966); John
Campbell, "The Greek Civil War," in Evan
Luard, ed., The International Regulation of Civil
War (New York: New York University Press, 1972),
pp. 53, 59; Middle East International, 9 September
1988, pp. 3-4 [henceforth MEI].
12. For example, Peter Calvert, Revolution and
International Politics (London: Frances Pinter,
1984); Harry Eckstein, "On the Etiology of Internal
War", in George Kelly and Clifford Brown, eds.,
Struggle in the State: Sources and Patterns of
World Revolution (New York: John Wiley & Son,
1970), p. 189; Nathan Leites and Charles Wolf Jr.,
Rebellion and Authority: An Analytic Essay on Insurgent
Conflicts (Chicago: Markham Publishing, 1970),
pp. 76-78; Andrew M. Scott et al, Insurgency
(Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
1970), p. 77; Eqbal Ahmed, "Revolutionary Warfare
and Counterinsurgency," in Norman Miller and
Roderick Aya, eds., National Liberation: Revolution
in the Third World (New York: The Free Press,
1971), pp. 168-170; David Wilkinson, Revolutionary
Civil War: The Elements of Victory and Defeat
(Palo Alto, Calif.: Page-Ficklin, 1975), pp. 25-26;
Gerard Chaliand, ed., Guerilla Strategies (Berkley:
University of California Press, 1980), p. 16; Bard
E. O'Neill et al., Insurgency in the Modern World
(Boulder: Westview Press, 1980), pp. 15-16; Walter
Lacqueur, Guerilla: A Historical and Critical Study
(Boulder: Westview Press, 1984), p. 394. Notable exceptions
are Thomas H. Greene, Comparative Revolutionary
Movements 3rd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J: Prentice-Hall,
1990), pp. 110-111, 125-132; McColl, "A Political
Geography of Revolution," and J.D. Deiner, "Guerilla
Border Sanctuaries and Counter-insurgent Warfare,"
The Army Quarterly 109, 2 (April 1979)--although
the latter two studies tend to examine the question
from a counter-insurgency perspective, analyzing the
identification or destruction of guerilla base areas.
In the Palestinian case, relations between the PLO
and host governments are a central focus of Paul A.
Jureidini and William E. Hazen, The Palestinian
Movement in Politics (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington,
1973), wherein the issue is dealt with in largely
descriptive terms.
13. Douglas Anglin and Timothy Shaw, "Zambia
and Southern African Liberation Movements 1964-1974,"
Zambia's Foreign Policy: Studies in Diplomacy and
Dependence (Boulder: Westview Press, 1979), pp.
234-271.
14. O'Neill, Armed Struggle in Palestine,
p.160.
15. O'Neill, Armed Struggle in Palestine,
p. 160 suggests that "if an insurgent organization
finds it necessary to establish a parallel hierarchy
in an external support state, which governs part of
the state's territory and population, violent conflict
with the host state is almost inevitable."
16. Dan O'Meara, "Destabilization of the Frontline
States of Southern Africa," Canadian Institute
for International Peace and Security Background
Paper 20 (June 1988): 6-7.
17. The Accord prohibited guerilla organization,
recruitment and transit; logistics bases, training
centers, arms depots, command centers, telecommunication
facilities and radio broadcast facilities. The text
of the Nikomati Accord can be found in Ibrahim S.R.
Msabaha and Timothy M. Shaw, eds., Confrontation
and Liberation in Southern Africa: Regional Directions
After the Nikomati Accord (Boulder: Westview Press,
1987), pp. 279-283.
18. Edgar O'Ballance, The Algerian Insurrection
1954-62 (Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books, 1967), p.
85; Saad Jawad, Iraq and the Kurdish Question 1958-70
(London: Ithaca Press, 1981), p. 297.
19. Examining the linkage between the two, James
Rosenau has differentiated between "personnel
wars" (concerned with the composition of the
existing political elite), "authority wars"
(concerned with the arrangement of political power),
and "structural wars" (which challenge the
substructures of society). The latter--corresponding
with the concept of revolutionary insurgency as used
in this study--involve more extensive international
repercussions. See: "Internal War as an International
Event," in James N. Rosenau, ed., International
Aspects of Civil Strife (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1964), pp. 45-91; Karl W. Deutsch,
"External Involvement in Internal War,"
in Harry Eckstein, ed., Internal War: Problems
and Approaches (New York: The Free Press, 1964);
George A. Kelly and Linda B. Miller, Internal War
and International Systems: Perspectives on Method,
Occasional Paper No. 21 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
Center for International Affairs, 1969).
20. K.J. Holsti has found external intervention in
almost half of 200 cases of revolutions during 1900-1950;
see Holsti, International Politics: A Framework
for Analysis 3rd edition (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall, 1977), p. 275.
21. Clinton Bailey, Jordan's Palestinian Challenge,
1948-1983: A Political History (Boulder: Westview
Press, 1984).
22. This tendency may be reinforced by the unwillingness
of regular military officers to accept the indigenous
nature of an insurgency--and hence look for an external
actor that can be blamed for insurgent actions, and
engaged in conventional warfare. Eqbal Ahmed, "Revolutionary
Warfare and Counterinsurgency," p. 168.
23. International law has traditionally enjoined
states to refrain from assisting insurgencies against
established governments, and to assume neutrality
in the event of full-scale civil war. Richard Falk,
ed., The International Law of Civil War (Baltimore:
The John Hopkins Press, 1971), pp. 11-16; Rosalyn
Higgins, "International Law and Civil Conflict",
in Luard, ed., The International Regulation of
Civil Wars; James E. Bond, The Rules of Riot:
Internal Conflict and the Law of War (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1974), pp. 99-102; John
North Moore, ed., Law and Civil War in the Modern
World (Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press,
1974); Françoise Hampson, "Winning by
the Rules: Law and Warfare in the 1980s," Third
World Quarterly 11, 2 (April 1989). A state's
"right" of reprisal or hot pursuit is less
clear; see Richard Falk, "The Beirut Raid and
the International Law of Retaliation," American
Journal of International Law 63 (July 1969); Yehuda
Blum, "The Beirut Raid and the International
Double Standard," American Journal of International
Law 64 (January 1970).
24. O'Meara, "Destabilization of the Frontline
States of Southern Africa, 1980-1987," pp. 5-6;
Robert S. Jaster, "South Africa and its Neighbours:
The Dynamics of Regional Conflict," International
Institute for Strategic Studies Adelphi Papers
209 (Summer 1986): 62-73.
25. Arnold Fraleigh, "The Algerian Revolution
as a Case Study in International Law," in Falk,
ed., The International Law of Civil War, pp.
206-207; J. K. Cillier, Counter-Insurgency in Rhodesia
(London: Croom Helm, 1985), pp. 173-174.
26. The use of covert action against sanctuary states
is well established in the literature on counter-insurgency,
e.g. Roger Trinquier, Modern Warfare (New York:
Praeger, 1964), pp. 101-103; John McCuen, The Art
of Counter-Revolutionary War (London: Faber &
Faber, 1966), pp. 240-249. In the case of South Africa,
Pretoria has supported UNITA guerillas against Angola,
the "Mozambique National Resistance" (itself
originally a creation of the Rhodesian regime) against
Mozambique, "Super-ZAPU" in Zimbabwe, and
the "Lesotho Liberation Army" in Lesotho.
Steven Metz, "Pretoria's `Total Strategy' and
Low-Intensity Warfare in Southern Africa," Comparative
Strategy 6, 4 (1987): 437-469.
27. US encouragement to Honduras and Costa Rica to
provide shelter and aid to Nicaraguan rebel forces
represents perhaps the most obvious example of an
external actor influencing insurgent-sanctuary relations
in this way--although in this case, the Contra's dependence
on the US made Washington, and not the Contra leadership,
the prime initiator of policy. See US House of Representatives
and Senate, Report of the Congressional Committees
Investigating the Iran-Contra Affair (Washington,
D.C.: United States Government Printing Office, 1987).
28. Bahgat Korany, "The Take-Off of Third World
Studies: The Case of Foreign Policy," World
Politics 35, 3 (April 1983); Bahgat Korany, How
Foreign Policy Decisions are Made in the Third World:
A Comparative Analysis (Boulder: Westview Press,
1986), pp. 40-41; Ali Dessouki and Bahgat Korany,
"A Literature Survey and Framework for Analysis,"
in Korany and Dessouki, The Foreign Policies of
Arab States (Boulder: Westview, 1984), pp. 5-18.
With regard to the PLO, Paul Noble has noted the need
for "a more systematic treatment of the factors
shaping policy and greater effort to link the internal
and external setting of [the PLO] to its actual behavior,"
Canadian Journal of Political Science 18, 1
(March 1985): 193-194.
29. Korany, Foreign Policy Decisions, p. 169;
Korany and Dessouki, "The Global System and Arab
Foreign Policies: The Primacy of Constraints,"
and Paul Noble, "The Arab System: Opportunities,
Constraints, and Pressures," both in Korany and
Dessouki, Foreign Policies of Arab States.
30. The importance of objective factors in shaping
both the outcomes and process of PLO policy-making
is emphasized by Khalidi, Under Siege, pp.
67-129.
31. Korany, Foreign Policy Decisions, p.170;
Korany and Dessouki, Foreign Policies of Arab States,
p. 326.
32. The impact of domestic political constraints
on foreign policy formation are examined by Barbara
Salmore and Stephen Salmore, "Political Regimes
and Foreign Policy," in Maurice East, Stephen
Salmore, and Charles Hermann, eds., Why Nations
Act: Theoretical Perspectives for Comparative Foreign
Policy Studies (Beverley Hills, Calif.: Sage,
1978), pp. 103-122. The importance of internal political
forces (and the influence on those forces of social
and external factors) are stressed by Alain Gresh,
PLO: The Struggle Within (London: Zed, 1985).
33. Korany, Foreign Policy Decisions, p.171.
34. Aaron David Miller, The PLO and the Politics
of Survival, Georgetown Center for Strategic and
International Studies, Washington Papers 99 (New York:
Praeger, 1983). This is evident in other policy-making
groups based on organizational representatives. Charles
Hermann writes of "delegate groups" in foreign
policy formation: "participants are likely to
feel cross-pressured between loyalty to the decision
structure...and to the organizations they represent....
Instead of appeals to group loyalty...the primary
process becomes incremental bargaining among group
members.... Trade-offs, logrolling, and compromises
tend to be prominent..." Similarly, in "leader-delegate
groups" (corresponding to a national front with
a dominant member), Hermann notes that new courses
of action tend to be expressed in terms sufficently
broad as to cover possible disagreements. Hermann,
"Decision Structure and Process Influences on
Foreign Policy," in East, Salmore, and Hermann,
eds., Why Nations Act, pp. 86-88.
35. Mohammed Selim, "The Survival of a Non-State
Actor: The Foreign Policy of the Palestine Liberation
Organization," in Korany and Dessouki, Foreign
Policies of Arab States, p. 198. See also Judy
Bertelson, The Palestinian Arabs: A Non-State System
Analysis (Beverley Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1979).
36. The concepts of "sensitivity" and "vulnerability"
are used here in the sense developed by Robert Keohane
and Joseph Nye, Power and Interdependence: World
Politics in Transition (Boston: Little, Brown
& Co., 1977), pp. 11-19. |